SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
 númeroESP5Atenção à saúde na doença falciforme em alagoas: aspectos da vulnerabilidade programática na pessoa adultaA importância das certificações ecológicas e das tic na promoção do turismo sustentável - estudo de caso de uma unidade de turismo rural índice de autoresíndice de assuntosPesquisa de artigos
Home Pagelista alfabética de periódicos  

Serviços Personalizados

Journal

Artigo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • Não possue artigos similaresSimilares em SciELO

Compartilhar


Millenium - Journal of Education, Technologies, and Health

versão impressa ISSN 0873-3015versão On-line ISSN 1647-662X

Mill  no.esp5 Viseu jun. 2020  Epub 30-Jun-2020

https://doi.org/10.29352/mill0205e.36.00234 

Engineering, technology, management and tourism

Corporate governance and debt structure: the case of portuguese smes

O governo empresarial e a estrutura da dívida: o caso das pme portuguesas

Gobierno corporativo y estructura de la deuda: el caso de las pymes portuguesas

António Pedro Pinto1  2 

Carla Manuela Henriques1  3 

José Manuel Rodrigues1 

1 Instituto Politécnico de Viseu, Escola Superior de Tecnologia e Gestão, Viseu, Portugal

2 Centro de Investigação em Serviços Digitais - CISeD, Viseu, Portugal

3 Centro de Matemática da Universidade de Coimbra, Coimbra, Portugal


Abstract

Introduction:

The study of corporate governance in financial decisions has gained relevance, particularly in debt structure, while remaining open how its characteristics influence such decisions. In this study, three forms of debt were considered (total, short term and medium/long term).

Objectives:

The study aims to analyze whether government influences corporate financing decisions, bearing in mind the nature of ownership (family vs. non-familiar).

Methods:

Multiple linear regression models to explain debt variables were estimated using least squares method with robust standard errors.

Results:

Family businesses have higher total indebtedness with managerial ownership playing a relevant role. Regardless of the property nature, higher return is associated with lower debt, while size has a positive impact on total debt. On the other hand, the nature of property is a differentiating factor in the way in which concentration of ownership is related to debt: In family-owned companies the concentration of ownership establishes a nonlinear (U-shaped) relationship with total indebtedness, but in non-family-owned companies the relationship between the two was not significant.

Conclusions:

Managerial ownership and concentration of ownership determine the debt structure differently in family and non-family businesses.

Keywords: property; corporate governance; debt structure; SMEs

Resumo

Introdução:

O estudo do governo empresarial nas decisões financeiras tem vindo a ganhar relevância, em particular, na estrutura de dívida, permanecendo em aberto, o modo como as suas características influenciam tais decisões. Consideraram-se três formas de endividamento (total, a curto prazo e a médio/longo prazo).

Objetivos:

O estudo pretende avaliar se o governo influência as decisões de financiamento das empresas, tendo presente a natureza da propriedade (familiar vs. não-familiar).

Métodos:

Recorreu-se à regressão linear múltipla para estimar os modelos explicativos das variáveis de endividamento e ao método dos mínimos quadrados com erros padrões robustos.

Resultados:

As empresas familiares apresentam maior endividamento total assumindo a propriedade interna um papel relevante. Independentemente da natureza de propriedade, maior rendibilidade está associada a menor endividamento, enquanto que a dimensão tem um impacto positivo no endividamento total. Por outro lado, nas empresas familiares a concentração de propriedade estabelece uma relação não linear (em forma de U) com o endividamento total, enquanto que nas não familiares a relação entre as duas variáveis não se revelou significativa.

Conclusões:

A propriedade interna e a concentração de propriedade determinam a estrutura de endividamento de forma diferenciada nas empresas familiares e não familiares.

Palavras-chave: propriedade; governo empresarial; estrutura da divida; PME´s

Resumen

Introducción:

El estudio del gobierno corporativo en las decisiones financieras ha ganado relevancia, particularmente en la estructura de la deuda, mientras permanece abierto cómo sus características influyen en tales decisiones. En este estudio, se consideraron tres formas de deuda (total, corto plazo y mediano/largo plazo).

Objetivos:

El estudio tiene como objetivo analizar si el gobierno influye en las decisiones de financiamiento corporativo, teniendo en cuenta la naturaleza de la propiedad (familiar versus no familiar).

Métodos:

Se estimaron modelos de regresión lineal múltiple para explicar las variables de deuda utilizando el método de mínimos cuadrados con errores estándar robustos.

Resultados:

Las empresas familiares tienen un mayor endeudamiento total y la propiedad gerencial desempeña un papel relevante. Independientemente de la naturaleza de la propiedad, un mayor rendimiento está asociado con una menor deuda, mientras que el tamaño tiene un impacto positivo en la deuda total. Por otro lado, en las empresas familiares, la concentración de la propiedad establece una relación no lineal (en forma de U) con el endeudamiento total, pero en empresas no familiares la relación entre los dos no fue significativa.

Conclusiones:

La propiedad interna y la concentración de propiedad determinan la estructura de la deuda de manera diferente en las empresas familiares y no familiares.

Palavras Clave: propiedad; gobierno corporativo; estructura de la deuda; PYME

Introduction

In recent years small and medium enterprises (SMEs) have been subject of numerous studies for their capacity to generate work and for the role they play as creators of wealth. The difficulties SMEs have in obtaining financial resources together with the scant possibility of access to capital markets means that the credit market constitutes their main source of funding. For this reason, studying corporate governance and bank intermediation becomes of particular relevance particularly in debt maturity (Diego, 2017). Relationships with their creditors play a particularly important role for companies subject to greater information asymmetry.

A key issue concerning every firm is the choice of its capital structure, the debt structure, its impact on firm’s performance and the role of associated agency conflicts are extensively researched topics. A number of specific factors, such as the nature of ownership, play an important role in determining debt as they can reduce agency costs and increase business value (Hayat, Yu, Man, and Jebran, 2018). Seminal papers by Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Grossman and Hart (1982) create an image of a firm with separation of ownership from management, where clash of interests of two groups (owners and managers) demands control mechanisms to reduce resulting agency costs. The core of corporate governance is to implement and ensure such controlling mechanisms that balance interests of stakeholders of a firm and reduce agency costs. Implementing control mechanisms that ensure different interests of stakeholders and reduce agency costs is the main objective of corporate governance, with ownership structure playing a relevant role.

Our study contributes to the existing literature in different ways. This article identifies previous relationships between managerial ownership and debt structure (e.g. Florackis and Ozkan, 2009; Lundstrum, 2009). It also considers that the nature and concentration of ownership, the number of managers and shareholders are variables that help to capture more fully the way companies are managed. The analysis focuses on the institutional context of Portuguese SMEs which has specific characteristics: Portuguese companies have a very high concentration of ownership, contrasting for example the UK reality characterized by a very dispersed ownership and a high concentration of institutional holdings (Lundstrum , 2009). Moreover, the institutional context and the legal protection of the rights of Portuguese creditors and shareholders fit the continental model, which is distinct from the Anglo-Saxon model, namely in financial distress situations (Rajan and Zingales, 1995). The managers of Portuguese companies are more conservative, the size of companies is smaller and the capital market is less developed. Secondly, we broaden the scope of previous studies (e.g. Lundstrum, 2009, Allaya, Derouiche and Muessig, 2018)) by studying the extent to which nature and concentration of ownership condition debt policies.

In corporate governance, ownership structure is a crucial instrument in alleviating agency problems (Sun, Ding, Guo, and Li, 2016). Ownership concentration enables the controller to have massive influence in policy-making, particularly in the capital structure decision (e.g. Liu and Sun, 2010; Paramanantham, Ting and Kweh, 2018). Previous researches have emphasised the association between ownership concentration and corporate financing, with particular focus on capital structure decision (e.g. Bunkanwanicha, Gupta and Rokhim, 2008; Liu, Tian, and Wang, 2011). Only a few studies examined the association between ownership concentration and debt structure (Shyu and Lee, 2009).

Shareholders with concentrated ownership are found to help minimise agency problems through capital structure decision. Thus, understanding how ownership concentration affects debt structure is important. The shareholders can monitor and control their companies by deciding on their debt structure. Generally, shareholders favour debt financing in the companies to discipline and monitor managers’ activities, and thus, ownership concentration is associated with high debt levels (Paramanantham, et al 2018). Driffield, Mahambre and Pal (2007) found ownership concentration positively affects the leverage of family companies in Malaysia, Thailand, and Indonesia. This finding was corroborated by Pindado and La Torre (2011) namely, the existence of a positive relationship between ownership concentration and leverage. On the other hand, many scholars agree shareholders prefer debt rather than equity financing to retain their control in the firm and avoid ownership dilution (e.g. Lundstrum, 2009; Zhang, 2013). They explain that controlling shareholders generally supervise and control the discretionary activity of managers via debt financing (Paramanantham, et al 2018).

However, other studies point to a negative link between ownership concentration and leverage on debt level. Short, Keassey and Dexbury (2002) for example found large external shareholdings are negatively related to debt level. This is a result of active engagement of external shareholders in controlling management in debt restructuring. In companies with high concentration of ownership, agency costs are low and therefore shareholders do not use debt as an instrument to control managers (Zhang, 2013).

The relationship between managerial ownership and capital structure has been particularly prominent in literature (eg. Chung, 2012; Ganguli, 2013, Hayat, Wang and Ma, 2016). Empirical evidence shows significant differences between countries. Few studies ( e.g. Short, Keasey and Duxbury,2002; Brailsford, Oliver and Pua, 2002; Pindado and De La Torre, 2011) have considered the nonlinear relationship between managerial ownership and debt. They also considered the interaction between managerial ownership with its impact on debt. Again the results from these few studies do not match.

Hayat et al. (2016) refer that the relationship between managerial ownership and debt has further complications. According to Short et al. (2002), managerial ownership increases the discretionary power of managers. Managers get more control over the financial decisions like reduction of debt. They get more control over the firm and make financing decisions in their favour. Ganguli (2013) finds that entrenched management with comparatively less debt and no outside monitoring increases agency costs.

This study intends to make a contribution in this field in the context of Portuguese SMEs. Thus, its main objective is to study the effect of ownership in terms of the nature and structure of property in the maturity of corporate debt.

This work it is organized as follows: the importance of corporate governance and relationship bank in debt structure is reviewed in the next section; Section 3 presents the methodology, data and variables used; Section 4 presents the main results obtained and finally, the main conclusions of this study are discussed in Section 5.

1. Survey of the literature

Corporate governance incorporates a set of concerns that have received particular attention (Salas, 2002). The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD, 2004) describes it as a system through which business is managed and controlled, specifying the rights and obligations of the different participants: the board of directors, management, shareholders, etc. This system sets out the rules and procedures for decision making, defines the structure by which objectives are set and provides the means to achieve and control them. Tirole (2006) states that the company's governance is a set of institutions that induces managers to internalize the interests of the stakeholders that participate in it.

The separation of ownership and control creates conflicts of interest between investors (owners and creditors) and management, hence the need to develop internal and external control mechanisms capable of harmonizing them, given the difficulty in completing contracts to resolve them (Baysinger and Hoskisson, 1990). Investors provide financial resources that need to be remunerated, and the company must implement a set of mechanisms that prevent some stakeholders from being privileged with value creation (Prowse, 1995).

From the above, it has been difficult to gather consensus on the concept of "corporate governance", a probable symptom of its complexity and scope. In spite of this, all the definitions have in common the idea that there is a question of sharing of power and results between the different parties, whose interests are not always coincident.

The managers prefer to have greater control over the company's decisions than the banks are willing to grant, and also contribute to reducing this dependence. Empirically Hoshi et al. (1993) observed that the greater the free cash flow of the company, the greater the incentive of owners and managers to reduce dependence on and control over banks.

The corporate governance literature has given importance to contractual problems between capital holders and managers and to the study of the mechanisms available to investors to control their resources and minimize conflicts. However, the work carried out on the concentration of ownership gives a new focus to the theory of the agency: it moves the main / agent relationship to the connection between majority and minority owners where the expropriation of "private benefits" takes on a preponderant role, provoking conflicts of interest (La Porta et al., 2000, Gregoric and Vespro, 2003).

The considerations made throughout this section are intended to study large companies. However, in the field of business finance, SMEs have gained greater importance because of the particularities they contain. These include the family nature of the ownership and control structure, which means that the contractual relations established in the company, as well as economic ties, often include family ties. In the first generation, the ownership of these companies is concentrated in the family nucleus and the direction usually falls to the founder. This coincidence between ownership and direction reduces agency costs caused by the conflict of interests between the principal and the agent. The relations that are established are very intense and can provide externalities that are manifested by a greater commitment, trust and loyalty between the contracting parties. All the participants of the company have a greater predisposition to value them, given the trust placed in the legitimate behaviour of the founder. However, relationships become more complex as the business grows and is subject to succession processes. New generations arise, ownership fragments, information asymmetries are greater, and agency problems increase between direction and ownership. The problems of agency are more difficult to solve, insofar as contractual relations coexist with family relationships (Schulze et al., 2001). Management positions in this type of business tend to remain within the family, without sufficient capacity being assured to perform this function, which can lead to significant losses for the company. The fact that the relationships between the stakeholders are based on family ties can condition not only the creation of value but also the way in which it is shared by the participants. The origins of power, within any company, provide the rights of control over resources or the existence of asymmetric information (Schulze et al., 2002). In the case of the family business there is another source of power that comes from the fact that the participant is a member of the controlling family. This duality gives it a privileged position within the organization, enabling it to enjoy "private benefits". The power obtained by the rights conferred by the resources is legitimate, contrary to the information asymmetry and kinship relations that allow the expropriation of income generated by other resources. Therefore, in addition to the mechanisms necessary to any organization, complementary mechanisms should be established to regulate family relations.

An open question that has gained relevance in the literature is related to the needs and characteristics of financing companies, associated with the nature of ownership. Céspedes et al. (2010) report that Latin American companies tend to seek capital debt, especially when loss of control is a problem. In turn, Brav (2009) finds that UK firms depend almost exclusively on foreign capital. In the same line, Anderson et al. (2003) and Ellul (2009) report that US family firms have higher indebtedness ratios relative to non-family members. Ellul (2009) recognizes that companies based in countries with high investor protection tend to have higher indebtedness values and, consequently, greater ability to attract foreign capital rather than equity.

Schulze et al. (2001) point out, however, that family businesses are not immune to high agency costs. This is due, in particular, to the absence of efficient capital market control, the inefficiency of the labour market in family businesses (eg. lack of promotion prospects for non-household managers) and self-esteem for family managers. Bopaiah (1998) also points out that the advantages associated with family leadership should be weighed against the drawbacks of family litigation, succession, and power struggles.

Another line of research that seeks to understand how companies are financed has underlying the asymmetry of information they are subject to in the credit and capital market. In this sense, Diamond (1984) states that banking intermediation plays an important role in collecting information by reducing the high levels of information asymmetry that family business are subject to. The information opacity associated with high levels of concentration of ownership generates moral hazard problems (Bopaiah, 1998), leading Hillbrecht (1999) to assert that shareholders must incur supervision costs and promote periodic detailed audits of minimize.

For Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), information asymmetry generates moral hazard and adverse selection problems, which causes an increase in the cost of external resources. The problem of moral hazard is posed a posteriori, unlike the adverse selection that is placed a priori. Adverse selection promotes an increase in the interest rate and gives rise to two effects of contradictory signals on the expected profitability of the bank: on the one hand, if clients comply with debt service, there is an expected increase in profitability, on the other hand, in the case of non-compliance, the risk increases and the profitability decreases (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981). From a certain amount, the second effect overlaps the first, situation in which an increase in the interest rate leads to the decrease in the profitability expected by the bank. Under these circumstances, the bank no longer has incentives to raise the interest rate, preferring to ration credit. Adverse selection and moral risk have counterproductive effects on bank profitability, since banks receive the amount contractually established, they do not benefit from the high profits of credit borrowers (when they occur), but in return they incur losses when company cannot comply with debt service.

The problems that the asymmetry of information originates in the credit market lead the banks to adopt screening techniques in the pre-contractual phase, speeding up the selection process of credit bidders. In the post-contractual phase, banks develop monitoring and control techniques by putting into practice a set of mechanisms capable of penalizing companies that deviate from the previously established and thus minimizing agency costs (Ramakrishnam and Thakor, 1984). One means of control exercised over the borrower is to use short- or medium-term bank debt to finance long-term projects. Thus, the company is forced to periodically renegotiate contractual conditions, requiring a "correct" behaviour to maintain it’s financing on reasonable terms until the end of the project (Diamond, 1984).

Petersen and Rajan (1995) point out that the relationships established with the banking entities are fundamental to the company and the increase in the number of banking entities may be associated with inefficiency of management, insofar as the control exercised by each entity is less efficient, a phenomenon called free-rider (Bolton and Scharfstein, 1996, Hart, 1995). The problem of the free-rider is caused by the presence of several financial intermediaries in situations in which the company is in financial difficulties. In this case, the entity granting additional credit bears all additional risk arising from an insolvency situation, but may only benefit from part of the profit on success, and no entity risks giving credit. Strong banking relationships are essential if young and small firms are to be financed under the best conditions. In this line Keasey K. et al. (2015) report that young family firms have a capital structure where equity is predominant.

Another current in the literature indicates that the higher levels of indebtedness in family companies come from agency conflicts with management. According to Stulz (1988) higher levels of indebtedness provide greater supervision. Households who do not participate in management can increase debt, thereby inducing greater oversight by creditors, reducing potential opportunistic behaviour of management.

Finally, when households exercise control, through participation in the management body, the levels of indebtedness are lower. Two arguments support this rationale: first, because family management is risk-averse, then because, according to agency theory, family involvement in management can lead to lower levels of debt as a consequence of the substitution effect of management: more direct monitoring of household management reduces the need for recourse to debt as a mechanism to prevent opportunistic management behaviour (Harford et al., 2008).

In addition to the constraints mentioned, Suto (2003) argues that the size of the company can also exert a positive influence on the use of indebtedness. Du and Dai (2005) suggest that the relationship between company size and indebtedness tends to be positive, due to economies of scale, stronger bargaining power among creditors, and the opportunity for diversification associated with less risk of non-compliance.

In turn, the profitability, and according to the theory of pecking order, establishes an inverse relation with the recourse to the debt. This is because the conflict of interests between internal and external creditors leads to a preference for internal resources relative to external financing (Suto, 2003). Profitability can, however, be positively associated with recourse to debt, as lenders tend to lend more credit to firms with higher cash flows (Rajan and Zingales, 1995).

2. Methods

An important issue in business financing decisions stems from the relevance of different attributes (internal and external) (Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Hall, Hutchinson, Michaelas, 2004). Corporate governance, the costs of financial and agency difficulties associated with debt, profitability, growth, asset structure, size and age, have been associated with levels of indebtedness and suggested as business determinants of capital structure (Watson and Wilson, 2002; Sogorb-Mira, 2005; Heyman, Svaleryd and Vlachos, 2013; Degryse, de Goeij and Kappert, 2012). Several other variables have been considered in the literature as determinants of indebtedness, such as the nature of the property, the ownership concentration, the managerial ownership, the number of managers, the profitability and the number of banks (Chung and Chan, 2012, Pinto and Augusto, 2014).

Three dependent variables are considered is this study to measure indebtedness: Short-term debt, medium and long-term debt and total debt (Table 1). Besides the dependent variables, Table 1 presents the independent variables considered in this study, demarcating the control variables.

The sample used in this study includes records of 14 203 SMEs listed in the Iberian Balances Analysis System (SABI) database. This data base contains information about Portuguese and Spanish companies, but only SMEs that met the following criteria were included in the sample:

  • Firms in the field of activity of manufacturing activity;

  • Number of employees between 5 and 250;

  • Complete information regarding the studied variables.

Table 1 Dependent and independent variables 

The financial information obtained from SABI relates to the year 2014. For data description, percentages are used for categorical variables, and means, with standard deviations (SD), for quantitative variables. The comparison between family and non-family firms, with respect to quantitative variables, was carried out with t-test. Applying Principal Component Analysis, the three variables considered as measures of the size of the companies were reduced to a single dimension indicator. Multiple linear regression models were estimated to explain each of the three debt variables considered in this study. However, given that family firms have specific characteristics that differentiate them in many aspects of non-family firms, we have chosen to analyse separately these two groups of companies. Thus, for family and for non-family firms, and for each of the three debt variables, the following model was considered:

Eq1

Each model was estimated by ordinary least squares. The significance of the variables was evaluated based on robust standard errors, since evidence of heteroskedasticity was found (Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity). Nonsignificant variables were removed from the models.

All statistical analysis was performed with SPSS (Statistical Package for the Social Sciences), version 24, and STATA, version 14.

3. Results

Among the 14 203 enterprises of the sample, 12 218 (86%) are family businesses. Table 2 presents the mean and standard deviation of the debt variables for family and non-family firms. For family firms, significantly higher levels of indebtedness were found, either in terms of medium and long-term debt or of total indebtedness. For short term debt, a higher mean value was found for family firms but, at the level of 0.05, no significance could be established.

Table 2 Summary statistics for the dependent variables 

Family firms also have significantly higher values of managerial ownership, number of shareholders and performance (ROA) (Table 3), while, for the remaining variables, lower values for family firms was found.

Table 3 Summary statistics for the independent variables 

Several regression models were estimated for each measure of indebtedness, with non-significant variables being removed one at a time.

Regression coefficients for total indebtedness are reported in Table 4. For family firms, the model explains 8% of total debt variation. Managerial ownership has a positive effect on total indebtedness, as does the size. On the contrary, ceteris paribus, the increase in the number of managers, in the performance (ROA) and in the number of banks contributes to the decrease of total indebtedness. The ownership concentration initially has a negative but decreasing effect on total indebtedness, but this effect becomes positive and increasing to higher values of ownership concentration, since the square of this variable has a positive significant coefficient. More precisely, as the concentration of ownership increases to a certain extent, indebtedness decreases, but with a diminishing effect. From a certain point the effect becomes positive and increasing.

The model estimated for non-family firms provides evidence that size has a positive effect on total indebtedness (Table 4), but, on the contrary, the number of managers, the performance and the number of banks are negatively associated with total indebtedness. That is, ceteris paribus, large firms tend to have high levels of total indebtedness, while companies with high ROA values, or with many managers or with many banks tend to have low levels of total indebtedness. The model explains 6.7% of the variation of total indebtedness.

Table 4 The OLS regression results for total indebtedness 

For short-term debt (Table 5), the estimated model for family firms reveals a relation of debt with the independent variables similar to the one obtained for total indebtedness. Managerial ownership has a positive effect on short-term debt, as does the size. On the other hand, ceteris paribus, a large number of managers or of the number of banks, as well as a high ROA, contributes to reduce short-term debt. For the ownership concentration, a non-linear relationship of the same type as that established for total indebtedness was observed: for lower values of ownership concentration, the effect is negative but decreasing, eventually becoming positive and increasing to higher values of ownership concentration.

Table 5 The OLS regression results for short-term debt 

For non-family firms, the model provides evidence that ownership concentration has a positive relation with short-term debt and with size (Table 5). On the other hand, ceteris paribus, firms with a high number of managers, ROA, age or number of banks tend to have a lower short-term debt.

Analysing medium and long-term debt (Table 6), there is no evidence that managerial ownership has any effect on the level of indebtedness, neither for family nor for non-family firms. As in previous models, the regression coefficient for performance (measured by ROA) is negative and significant. Regarding the number of managers, for family firms, the sign of the coefficient remained negative, but for non-family firms it is positive. Thus, in contrast to what was observed for the other indebtedness variables, in non-family companies, a higher number of managers is associated with higher levels of medium and long-term debt. Similarly, the coefficient of ownership concentration has opposite sign for family and non-family businesses, being positive for the former and negative for the latter. Furthermore, for family companies, there is also a negative and significant association with the number of banks, while for non-family businesses this variable is no longer significant. For non-family firms the maturity (age) is also significantly related with medium and long-term debt, more precisely, ceteris paribus, older firms tend to have lower levels of medium and long-term debt.

Table 6 The OLS regression results for medium and long-term debt 

Conclusions

In this study, using a sample of 14 203 Portuguese SMEs, cross-sectional, additional empirical evidence is provided for the effect of government on debt structure. This issue is of particular importance for companies at the level of aggregate economic activity, financial stability and even at the level of the financial system architecture. In addition, our empirical analysis focuses on SMEs, which represent over 99.5% of the Portuguese economy, where the banking system plays a central role in financing these businesses units.

This study expands the knowledge of debt structure inducers emphasizing the importance of the relationship between corporate governance and the structure of debt in the Portuguese context, using two proxies: property nature and property structure.

This study provides evidence that the higher the performance, the lower the indebtedness, regardless of whether or not the company is familiar. Furthermore, either for family or non-family firms, the company size has a positive impact on the total debt and short-term debt. Moreover, family and non-family businesses are similar in the relation that total debt and short-term debt establish with the number of banking institutions and the number of managers (as these numbers increase, levels of indebtedness decrease).

However, results suggest that the debt structure is clearly distinct when one considers the nature of ownership. Significantly higher values of indebtedness were found for family firms. Also, management ownership is a determinant factor in the way family businesses structure their indebtedness but is not relevant in non-family ones. In addition, in family firms, ownership concentration has a non-linear U-shaped relation with total debt and short-term debt. For non-family firms, this study revealed a linear positive relation of ownership concentration with the short-term debt, but no significant relation was found with total debt.

The main constraint of this study stems from the difficulty of collecting information and the fact that a significant number of studies focus on countries with very different legal, regulatory and market institutions from the Portuguese reality.

An important limitation of this study is that it only contemplates cross section data of the year 2014; a panel data study and more recent information would be desirable. Panel data methodologies allow us to characterize the change in the response variable over time and the factors that influence this change and can provide more efficient estimates.

In spite of the identified limitations, the study allowed us to deepen our knowledge of the impact that corporate governance (in particular the nature of ownership) has on debt maturity.

As a future work proposal, this research should be extended to other sectors of activity, besides manufacturing, in the context of Portuguese SMEs, and broaden the time horizon under study. Another line of inquiry should incorporate other features of corporate governance enriching the proposed empirical model.

Acknowledgments

This work is funded by National Funds through the FCT - Foundation for Science and Technology, I.P., within the scope of the project Refª UIDB/05583/2020. Furthermore, we would like to thank the Research Centre in Digital Services (CISeD) and the Polytechnic of Viseu for their support.

References

Allaya, M., Derouiche, I., & Muessig, A. (2018). Voluntary disclosure, ownership structure, and corporate debt maturity: A study of French listed firms.International Review of Financial Analysis. (Article in press) [ Links ]

Anderson, R. C., Mansi, S.A., & Reed, D. M. (2003). Founding family ownership and the agency cost of debt. Journal of Financial Economics, 68(2), 263-285. [ Links ]

Baysinger, B., & Hoskisson, R.E. (1990). The composition of boards of directors and strategic control: effects on corporate strategy. Academy of Management Review, 15(1), 72-87. [ Links ]

Bolton, P., & Scharfstein, D. (1996). Optimal debt structure and the number of creditors. Journal of Political Economy, 104(1), 1-25. [ Links ]

Bopaiah, C. (1998). Availability of credit to family business. Small Business Economics, 11(1), 75-86. [ Links ]

Brailsford, T. J., Oliver, B. R., & Pua, S. L. (2002). On the Relation Between Ownership Structure and Capital Structure. Accounting & Finance, 42(1), 1-26. [ Links ]

Brav, O. (2009). Access to capital, capital structure, and the funding of the firm. Journal of Finance, 64, 263-308. [ Links ]

Bunkanwanicha, P., Gupta, J., & Rokhim, R. (2008). Debt and entrenchment: Evidence from Thailand and Indonesia. European Journal of Operational Research, 185(3), 1578-1595. [ Links ]

Céspedes, J., González, M., & Molina, C. (2010). Ownership and capital structure in Latin America. Journal of Business Research, 63, 248-254. [ Links ]

Chung, C. Y. (2012) Substitutability Between Institutional Monitoring and Debt Monitoring. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 101. [ Links ]

Chung, M., & Chan, T. (2012). Ownership structure, family leadership, and performance of affiliate firms in large family business groups. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29(2), 303-329. [ Links ]

Clarkson, M. (1995). A stakeholder framework for analyzing and evaluating corporate social performance. Academy of Management Review, 2081, 92-117. [ Links ]

Degryse, H., de Goeij, P., & Kappert, P. (2012). The impact of firm and industry characteristics on small firms’ capital structure. Small Business Economics, 38(4), 431-44. [ Links ]

Diamond, D. (1984). Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies, 51(3), 393-414. [ Links ]

Diego, P. (2017). Sovereign debt maturity structure under asymmetric information. Journal of International Economics, 108(1), 243-259. [ Links ]

Dittmar, A., & Mahrt-Smith, J. (2007). Corporate governance and the value of cash holdings. Journal of Financial Economics, 83(3), 599-634. [ Links ]

Driffield, N., Mahambre, V., & Pal, S. (2007). How does ownership affect capital structure and firm value: Recent evidence from East Asia. CEDI Discussion Paper Series Working Paper No. 07-04. West London: Brunel University. [ Links ]

Du, J., & Dai, Yi. (2005). Ultimate Corporate Ownership Structures and Capital Structures: Evidence from East Asian Economies. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 13 (1), 60-71. [ Links ]

Ellul, A. (2009). Control motivations and capital structure decisions. Working Paper, Indiana University. [ Links ]

Florackis, C., Kostakis, A., & Ozkan, A. (2009). Managerial ownership and performance. Journal of Business Research, 62(12), 1350-1357. [ Links ]

Ganguli, S. K. (2013). Capital Structure-Does Ownership Structure Matter? Theory and Indian Evidence. Studies in Economics and Finance, 30(1), 56-72. [ Links ]

Gillan, S. & Starks, L. (2000). Corporate governance proposals and shareholder activism: the role of institutional investors. Journal of Financial Economics, 57(2), 275-305. [ Links ]

Gorton, G., & Schmid, A. (2000). Universal Banking and the Performance of German Firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 29- 80. [ Links ]

Gregoric, A., & Vespro, C. (2003). Block Trades and the Benefits of Control in Slovenia. Working Paper No. 29/2003, http://ssrn.com/abstract=444500Links ]

Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1982). Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives. The Economics of Information and Uncertainty, University of Chicago Press, pp. 107-37. [ Links ]

Hall, G.C., Hutchinson, P.J., & Michaelas, N. (2004). Determinants of the capital structure of European SMEs. Journal of Business & Accounting, 31 (5-6), 711-728. [ Links ]

Harford, J., Li, K. & Zhao, X. (2008). Corporate Boards and the Leverage and Debt Maturity Choices. International Journal of Corporate Governance, 1(1), 3-27. [ Links ]

Hart, O. (1995). Corporate Governance: Some Theory and Implications. The Economic Journal, 105(430), 678-689. [ Links ]

Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1995). “Debt and Seniority: An Analysis of the Role of Hard Claims in Constraining Management.” American Economic Review, 85, no. 3: pp. 567-585. [ Links ]

Hayat, M., Yu, Y., Man, W., & Jebran, K. (2018). Impact of Managerial and Institutional Ownership on Capital Structure: A Comparison Between China & USA. European Journal of Business and Management, 10(24), 69-80. [ Links ]

Hayat, M., Wang, M., & Ma, J. (2016). The Impact of Ownership Structure on Corporate Debt Financing: Evidence from the Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan. The International Journal of Management Theory and Practices, 17, 92-109. [ Links ]

Heyman, F., Svaleryd, H., & Vlachos, J. (2013). Competition, takeovers, and gender discrimination. ILR Review, 66(2), 409-432. [ Links ]

Hillbrecht, R. (1999). Economia monetária. São Paulo, Atlas. [ Links ]

Hoshi, T., Kashyap, A., & Scharfstein, D. (1993). The choice between public and private debt: an analysis of post-deregulation corporate finance in Japan. NBER Working paper, 4421. Acedido em http://ssrn.com/abstract=227327Links ]

Jensen, M., & W. Meckling (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Cost and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-60. [ Links ]

Johnson, P., Boone, A., Breach, E. (2000). Corporate governance in the Asian financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 141-186. [ Links ]

Keasey, K., Martinez, B., & Pindado, J. (2015). Young family firms: Financing decisions and the willingness to dilute control. Journal of Corporate Finance, 34, 47-63. [ Links ]

La Porta, R., López de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Agency problems and dividend policies around the world. Journal of Finance, 55(1), 1-33. [ Links ]

Liu, G., & Sun, J. (2010). Ultimate ownership structure and corporate disclosure quality: Evidence from China. Managerial Finance, 36(5), 452-467. [ Links ]

Liu, Q., Tian, G., & Wang, X. (2011). The effect of ownership structure on leverage decision: New evidence from Chinese listed firms. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, 16(2), 254-276. [ Links ]

Lundstrum, L. L. (2009). Entrenched management, capital structure changes and firm value. Journal of Economics and Finance, 33(2), 161-175. [ Links ]

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2004). Os Princípios da OCDE sobre o Governo das Sociedades. Acedido em https://www.oecd.org/daf/ca/corporategovernanceprinciples/33931148.pdfLinks ]

Paramanantham, N. S., Ting, I. W. K., & Kweh, Q. L. (2018). Ownership concentration and debt structure: Evidence from top 100 PLCs in Malaysia. Institutions and Economies, 10(3), 1-13. [ Links ]

Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1995). The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 407-443. [ Links ]

Pindado, J., & La Torre, D. C. (2011). Capital structure: New evidence from the ownership structure. International Review of Finance, 11(2), 213-226. [ Links ]

Pinto, A., & Augusto, M., (2014). Are There Non-linear Relationships between Ownership Structure and Operational Performance?. Empirical Evidence from Portuguese SMEs Using Dynamic Panel Data. International Journal of Business Administration, 5(3), 1-19. [ Links ]

Prowse, S. (1995). Corporate governance in an international perspective. A survey of corporate control mechanisms among large firms in the US, UK, Japan and Germany. Financial Market, Institutions and Instruments, 4(1), 1-63. [ Links ]

Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1995). What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from international data”, Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1421-1460. [ Links ]

Ramakrishnam, R., & Thakor, A. (1984). Information reliability and theory of financial intermediation. Review of Economic Studies, 52, 415-432. [ Links ]

Salas, V. (2002). El gobierno de la empresa. Colección de Estudios Económicos, 29. [ Links ]

Schulze, W. S., Lubatkin, M. H., Dino, R. N., & Buchholtz, A. K. (2001). Agency relationships in family firms: Theory and evidence. Organization Science, 12(2), 99-116. [ Links ]

Schulze, W., Lubatkin, M., & Dino, R. (2002). Altruism, agency, and competitiveness of family firms. Managerial and Decision Economics, 23(4-5), 247-259. [ Links ]

Schulze, W., Lubatkin, M., Dino, R. & Buchholtz, A. (2001). Agency relationship in family firms: theory and evidence. Organization Science, 12(2), 99-116. [ Links ]

Short, H., Keasey, K., & Duxbury, D. (2002). Capital structure, management ownership and large external shareholders: A UK analysis. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 9 (3), 375-399. [ Links ]

Shyu, Y. W., & Lee, C. I. (2009). Excess Control Rights and Debt Maturity Structure in Family-Controlled Firms. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(5), 611-628. [ Links ]

Sogorb-Mira, F. (2005). How SME uniqueness affects capital structure: Evidence from a 1994-1998 Spanish data panel. Small Business Economics, 25(5), 447-457. [ Links ]

Stiglitz, J., & WEISS, A. (1981). Credit Rationing in Markets with imperfect information. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 393-410. [ Links ]

Sun, J., Ding, L., Guo, J. M., & Li, Y. (2016). Ownership, capital structure and financing decision: evidence from the UK. The British Accounting Review, 48(4), 448-463. [ Links ]

Stulz, R. (1988). Managerial control of voting rights: Financing policies and the market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics, 20(1-2), 25-54. [ Links ]

Suto, M. (2003). “Capital structure and investment behaviour of Malaysian firms in the 1990s: A study of corporate governance before the crisis. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 11(1), 25-39. [ Links ]

Tirole, J. (2006). The Theory of Corporate Finance. Princeton University Press, 15-20. [ Links ]

Watson, R., & Wilson, N., (2002). Small and medium size enterprise financing: A note on some of the empirical implications of a pecking order. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 29 (3‐4), 557-578. [ Links ]

Zhang, L. L. (2013). The impact of ownership structure on capital structure: Evidence from listed companies in China. The Journal of Finance and Economics, 12(1), 1-30. [ Links ]

Zingales, L. (1998). Corporate Governance. NBER, University of Chicago, Working Paper, 6309. [ Links ]

Received: March 20, 2019; Accepted: November 30, 2019

Corresponding Author António Pedro Pinto Escola Superior de Tecnologia e Gestão de Viseu Campus Politécnico 3504-510 Viseu - Portugal spinto@estv.ipv.pt

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License